Evaluative Satisfaction System (Pacifica): Difference between revisions

From TSP Encyclopedia
Jump to navigation Jump to search
(Intro, procedure, examples, and comparison sections)
Tag: 2017 source edit
 
(Decided to change the way constituency winners are chosen... again)
Tag: 2017 source edit
 
(2 intermediate revisions by the same user not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Short description|Approval-based semi-proportional electoral system}}
{{Short description|Approval-based semi-proportional electoral system}}
The '''Evaluative Satisfaction System (ESS)''' is a [[wikipedia:Mixed electoral system|mixed electoral system]] under which representatives are elected in a two-step process with a single round of [[wikipedia:Combined approval voting|combined approval voting]]. Representatives are first chosen for on a [[wikipedia:Electoral district|constituency]] level (which might comprise the entire electorate as a single constituency, albeit this would be impractical in large-scale elections), after which the overall result is made more [[wikipedia:Proportional representation|proportional]] by electing further representatives for underrepresented parties according to a [[wikipedia:Zweitmandat|best-loser algorithm]] on the basis of the constituency results. It was first developed for and used in the {{pa|2012 Tepertopian Assembly election}} with the intention to incentivize [[wikipedia:Strategic voting|voting honestly rather than strategically]].
The '''Evaluative Satisfaction System (ESS)''' is a {{wpl|mixed electoral system}} under which representatives in a multi-member body are elected on two tiers via a single round of {{wpl|combined approval voting|evaluative voting}}. Representatives are first chosen in {{wpl|Electoral district|constituencies}} as the lower tier by using a {{wpl|Majoritarian representation|majority approval vote}}; the overall composition of the body is then made to approach {{wpl|Proportional representation|proportionality}} on the upper tier using a {{wpl|Zweitmandat|best-loser algorithm}}.


ESS is a [[wikipedia:Semi-proportional representation|semi-proportional]] electoral system, since parties might win more constituencies in the first step than they would be proportionally entitled to in total, and the system does not compensate this by awarding other parties [[wikipedia:Leveling seat|leveling seats]] to make a purely proportional result possible again.
ESS is a {{wpl|Semi-proportional representation|semi-proportional}} electoral system, since parties might win more constituency seats in the lower tier than they would be proportionally entitled to in total, and the system does not compensate this by awarding other parties {{wpl|Leveling seat|leveling seats}} to make a purely proportional result on the upper tier possible again. This issue typically affects elections where there are too few upper-tier seats in comparison to constituency seats.
 
The system was first developed for and used in the {{pa|2006 Council of the Union election}} with the intention to reduce incentives for {{wpl|strategic voting}}. It has drawn both praise and criticism: Supporters laud that its straightforward ballot layout makes casting one's vote accessible and ballots hard to spoil unintentionally, as well as that the multiple different tallies from each ballot make the election relatively resistent to strategic voting; critics however complain that this very fact also renders elections intransparent by making it hard for voters to precisely see how their vote will influence ‒ and, even after polls close, how it actually did affect ‒ the results.


== Procedure ==
== Procedure ==


[[File:ESS Ballot 2021.jpg|thumb|An ESS Ballot for the {{pa|2021 Tepertopian Assembly election}}]]
[[File:2022_Tepertopia_Council_Election_Ballot.svg|thumb|An ESS Ballot for the {{pa|2022 Council of the Union election}}]]
Under ESS, each voter casts a single [[wikipedia:Combined approval voting|combined approval voting]] ballot: Any number of candidates they approve or disapprove of may be marked (called "approved" and "vetoed" in Tepertopian electoral law), also with the option to avoid marking ("evaluating") a candidate altogether. Candidates may be linked to a party or stand as independents.
Under ESS, each voter casts a single {{wpl|evaluative voting}} ballot: Any number of candidates they approve or disapprove of may be marked, with the option to avoid marking a candidate altogether to express indifference. Candidates may be linked to a party list or stand as independents.
 
=== First Step: Constituency Seats ===


In the first step of the election procedure, representatives are determined on the constituency level. Each constituency elects at least one local representative, but there is no theoretical limit on the number of representatives a constituency could elect. There isn't a strict need to have multiple constituencies, either - for small-scale elections, there might also be just a single constituency, but a usually exponentially greater number of candidates per additional seat limits the practicability of single-constituency elections.
=== Lower tier ===


To determine the elected representatives, the absolute number of approvals and disapprovals on each candidate is tallied. The candidate(s) having the highest number of approvals after subtracting the number of disapprovals received are elected as the representative(s) of the constituency. This majoritarian method of selecting constituency winners tends to produce landslide victories for the candidates of the most-supported party on the constituency level, as long as none of them are so relatively more disliked by the electorate that their number of disapprovals pushes them below other candidates.
In the first step of the election procedure, representatives are determined on the constituency level as the lower-tier seats. Each constituency elects at least one representative, but there is no theoretical limit on the number of representatives a constituency could elect. There isn't a strict need to have multiple constituencies, either ‒ for small-scale elections, having just a single multi-seat constituency is equally viable, but the number of candidates standing can grow quite quickly with an increasing amount of constituency seats, thus limiting the practicability of single-constituency elections.


As an alternative to the majoritarian method, the Tepertopian Electoral System commission (TESC) also suggested electing constituency winners proportionally by using the [[wikipedia:Sequential proportional approval voting|sequential proportional approval system]]; this however was not adopted by the {{pa|Tepertopian Assembly}}.
The exact method used to elect representatives is {{wpl|combined approval voting|evaluative voting}}: Voters mark both all candidates they approve of and all they disapprove of, with the option to abstan from evaluating a candidate altogether. Approvals and disapprovals are tallied up for each candidate, and the candidate(s) with the highest net approval ‒ calculated by subtracting the number of disapprovals they received from the number of approvals received ‒ win(s) the constituency's seat(s).


=== Second Step: Compensatory Seats ===
=== Upper tier ===


The second step of the procedure is more complicated. First, the parties eligible for compensatory seats have to be determined - the TESC suggested either using a traditional [[wikipedia:Electoral threshold|electoral threshold]], which would eliminate all parties whose candidates didn't, on average, surpass a set approval percentage, or to require that at least one representative of the party had to be elected in a constituency; the latter of which was adopted.
The second step, electing the upper-tier compensatory seats, works in a slightly more complicated way. First, the parties eligible for receiving compensatory seats need to be determined the Tepertopian implementation requires that a party's candidates cross a certain approval threshold, for which the lower-tier approvals are considered. If parliamentary fragmentation isn't too large a concern, an implementation could also just consider all parties eligible.


Once the eligible parties have been determined, the ballots need to be re-counted in a manner similar to the [[wikipedia:Satisfaction approval voting|satisfaction approval method]]: All ''approvals'' a voter gave out to candidates standing for eligible parties are assigned an equal share of the voter's "satisfaction" - essentially, their one vote is divided among all such candidates. The satisfaction thusly assigned to the candidates is then summed for each associated party, thereby determining the party's percentage of the satisfaction (vote) total. The party's share of total satisfaction is equal to the share of seats entitled to.
With the eligible parties determined, ballots are re-counted to determine the electorate's so-called ''satisfaction'' with the candidates of the eligible parties. Each voter's satisfaction is divided equally between all candidates they approved and who stand for eligible parties ‒ approvals towards independent candidates or candidates standing for ineligible parties are ignored. The satisfaction received by each candidates is then pooled for the associated parties to determine the overall satisfaction shares of the parties. Those relative shares then constitute the share of seats the party is ideally entitled to at-large.


Finally, the compensatory seats are handed out iteratively: Until all seats are filled, the party with the greatest difference between its share of seats entitled to and current actual seat share is selected, and from among its non-elected candidates, the one with the lowest percentage of disapproval - relative to the total number of ballots cast in the respective constituency - is elected to a compensatory seat. In the Tepertopian implementation, this level of the election features regional divisions with a fixed number of compensatory seats assigned to each as well in order to prevent disproportionate regional representation arising from the second step of the election: Once enough candidates from that region have been elected to compensatory seats, the region becomes barred from electing any more candidates for the second step, effectively removing all candidates within its boundaries from the lowest-disapproval consideration.
Once the shares stand, the compensatory upper-tier seats are handed out to the parties iteratively: Until all seats are filled, the most-underrepresented party (determined by the difference between its satisfaction share and current total seat share ‒ including those won on the lower tier) sees its least-disapproved candidate elected. Since upper-tier seats rely on unelected lower-tier candidates, parties have an incentive to stand candidates in as many constituencies as possible.


=== Example ===
=== Example ===


The constituency of Examplington encompasses the entire eponymous city, for which the three-seat municipal council is to be elected using ESS. Two parties (green and yellow) and one independent vie for the votes of the ten voters. Two of the three seats are to be elected in the first, the remaining one in the second step.
The constituency of Examplington encompasses the entire eponymous city, for which the three-seat municipal council is to be elected using ESS. Two parties (green and yellow) and one independent vie for the votes of the ten voters. Two of the three seats are to be elected on the lower, the remaining one on the upper tier.


The ballots come in as follows:
The ballots come in as follows:
Line 71: Line 71:
|}
|}


==== First Step ====
==== Lower tier ====


According to the results above, the candidate's net approval scores are as follows:
According to the results above, the candidate's net approval scores are as follows:
Line 79: Line 79:
! Approvals
! Approvals
! Disapprovals
! Disapprovals
! Net Approvals
! Net Approval
|-
|-
! {{font color|green|green|.}} A
! {{font color|green|green|.}} A
Line 88: Line 88:
! {{font color|green|green|.}} B
! {{font color|green|green|.}} B
| 4
| 4
| 3 + 2 = 5
| 3 + 2
| -1
| -1
|-
|-
! {{font color|yellow|yellow|.}} C
! {{font color|yellow|yellow|.}} C
| 3
| 3
| 4 + 1 = 5
| 4 + 1
| -2
| -2
|-
|-
! {{font color|yellow|yellow|.}} D
! {{font color|yellow|yellow|.}} D
| 3 + 1 = 4
| 3 + 1
| 2
| 2
| +2
| +2
|-
|-
! {{font color|gray|gray|.}} E
! {{font color|gray|gray|.}} E
| 2 + 1 = 3
| 2 + 1
| 0
| 0
| +3
| +3
|}
|}


As candidates A and E have the highest net approval, they are elected as representatives in the first step.
As candidates A and E have the highest net approval, they are elected as representatives on the lower tier.


==== Second Step ====
==== Upper tier ====


For the purposes of demonstration, Examplington does not impose any hurdles for parties to take before qualifying for compensatory seats. The independent E however does not play any role for the second step, since only party-affiliated candidates are considered for the satisfaction division - the two voters whose only positive approval was for E are consequently completely removed from second step calculations.
For the purposes of demonstration, Examplington qualifies all parties for compensatory seats without any restrictions. The independent E however does not play any role for upper-tier allocation, since only party-affiliated candidates are considered the two voters whose only positive approval went towards E are consequently completely removed from upper-tier calculations. As such, the satisfaction shares divide as such:


As such, voter satisfaction for each of the ballots divides as such:
{| class="wikitable
{| class="wikitable
! {{Diagonal split header|Candidate|Ballots}}
! {{Diagonal split header|Candidate|Ballots}}
Line 120: Line 119:
! 2×
! 2×
! 1×
! 1×
! Satisfaction
! Candidate Satisfaction
! Party Satisfaction
! Party Satisfaction
! Party Share
|-
|-
! {{font color|green|green|.}} A
! {{font color|green|green|.}} A
Line 130: Line 130:
| 2
| 2
| rowspan="2" | 4
| rowspan="2" | 4
| rowspan="2" | 50%
|-
|-
! {{font color|green|green|.}} B
! {{font color|green|green|.}} B
Line 145: Line 146:
| 1.5
| 1.5
| rowspan="2" | 4
| rowspan="2" | 4
| rowspan="2" | 50%
|-
|-
! {{font color|yellow|yellow|.}} D
! {{font color|yellow|yellow|.}} D
Line 153: Line 155:
| 2.5
| 2.5
|-
|-
! colspan="6" style="text-align=right;" | Satisfaction total:
! colspan="6" style="text-align:right;" | Total:
| 8
| 8
| 100%
|}
|}


In terms of satisfaction, the parties are split evenly - which makes sense considering that there were four ballots from voters only supporting the green party, three only supporting the yellow party, and one that supported a yellow party candidate and the independent. These shares of the total satisfaction determine the further procedure of the compensation algorithm, which runs the following steps once per seat to fill - in this case, only a single time, since only one seat remains to be filled on the council: First, the current share of seats each party has is determined, and then, the party with the greater difference between entitled and current seat share is awarded the seat.
In terms of party satisfaction, the parties are split evenly which makes sense, considering that there were four ballots from voters only supporting the green party, three only supporting the yellow party, and one that supported a yellow party candidate (and the ‒ irrelevant ‒ independent). These vote shares determine the further procedure of the compensation algorithm, which runs the following steps once per seat to fill in this case, only a single time, since only one seat remains to be filled on the council: First, the current share of seats each party has is determined, and then, the party with the greater difference between entitled and current seat share is awarded the seat.


{| class="wikitable"
{| class="wikitable"
Line 168: Line 171:
| Green
| Green
| 1
| 1
| 33%
| 1/3 = 33%
| 50%
| 50%
| 12%
| 12%
Line 174: Line 177:
| Yellow
| Yellow
| 0
| 0
| 0%
| 0/3 = 0%
| 50%
| 50%
| 50%
| 50%
|}
|}


As the yellow party is more under-represented than the green party, it is awarded the seat. Inside the party, the seat goes to the least-disapproved candidate from among the constituency candidates - in this case, candidate C from the yellow party received 5 disapprovals, and candidate D received 2. As such, the final seat is filled by candidate D.
As the yellow party is more under-represented than the green party, it is awarded the seat. Within the party, the seat goes to the least-disapproved candidate from among the constituency candidates in this case, candidate C from the yellow party received 5 disapprovals for a total disapproval rate of 50%, and candidate D received 2 for a rate of 20%. As such, the final seat is filled by candidate D.


This means that the municipal council of Examplington will have A from the green and D from the yellow party, as well as the independent E.
This means that the municipal council of Examplington will have A from the green and D from the yellow party, as well as the independent E.
Line 187: Line 190:
=== MMP ===
=== MMP ===


Unlike the [[wikipedia:Mixed-member proportional representation|Mixed-Member Proportional]] system, ESS does not natively accomodate for [[wikipedia:Overhang seat|overhang seats]] - since the system works on an iterative, relative share basis with a fixed number of seats, other parties are actively harmed by a party winning more seats on the constituency level than it would be entitled to in the compensation step: If a party would be entitled to 50% of the seats, but its competitor already won 60% in constituencies, a 100-seat parliament would be split 60-40 in seats under the ESS, while MMP would still award the party its absolute 50 seats, for a final 60-50 seat split. Some versions of MMP would furthermore fully compensate overhang seats with [[wikipedia:Leveling seat|leveling seats]] for the other parties, which would result in a fully proportional 60-60 seat split in the former example. Effectively, the ESS sacrifices this full proportionality in order to avoid ever-growing seat numbers stemming from overhang and leveling seats.
Unlike the {{wpl|Mixed-member proportional representation|Mixed-Member Proportional}} system, ESS does not natively accomodate for {{wpl|Overhang seat|overhang seats}} ‒ since the system works on an iterative, relative share basis with a fixed number of seats, other parties are actively harmed by a party winning more seats on the lower tier than it would be entitled to on the upper: If a party would be entitled to 50% of the seats, but its competitor already won a total of 60% in constituencies, a 100-seat parliament would be split 60-40 in seats under the ESS, while MMP would still award the party its absolute 50 seats for a final 60-50 seat split. Some versions of MMP would furthermore fully compensate overhang seats with {{wpl|Leveling seat|leveling seats}} for the other parties, which would result in a fully proportional 60-60 seat split in the former example. Effectively, the ESS sacrifices this full proportionality in order to avoid ever-growing seat numbers stemming from overhang and leveling seats.


Furthermore, most MMP implementations separate the candidate and the party vote, allowing voters to support local candidates without giving votes to the associated party ([[wikipedia:Split-ticket voting|split ticket]]), whereas ESS only exposes the candidates to voter approval and automatically converts their performance to party support to avoid [[wikipedia:Decoy list|decoy lists]]. However, ESS gives voters more options for influencing the order in which compensatory seats are awarded to candidates by using their disapproval count, whereas MMP usually features a [[wikipedia:Closed list|closed party list]], with the political parties fixing the order in which they want to have candidates elected in advance.
Furthermore, most MMP implementations separate the candidate and the party vote, allowing voters to support local candidates without giving votes to the associated party ({{wpl|split-ticket voting}}), whereas ESS only exposes the candidates to voter approval and automatically converts their performance to party support to avoid {{wpl|decoy lists}}. However, ESS gives voters more options for influencing the order in which compensatory seats are awarded to candidates by using their disapproval rate, whereas MMP often features a {{wpl|closed list}}, with the political parties fixing the order in which they want to have candidates elected in advance.


=== AMS ===
=== AMS ===


ESS is very similar to the [[wikipedia:Additional-member system|Additional-Member System]], which works the exact same on the overhang seat issue - essentially, ESS can be considered a sort of AMS, adapted to the use of Combined Approval Voting. However, AMS too often features split-ticket voting and closed party lists.
ESS is very similar to the {{wpl|Additional-Member System}}, which works the exact same on the overhang seat issue. Strictly speaking, ESS could be considered a variant of the AMS adapted to the use of Evaluative Voting. However, AMS too often features split-ticket voting and closed party lists.


=== MMM ===
=== MMM ===


[[wikipedia:Mixed-member majoritarian representation|Mixed-Member Majoritarian]] systems differ from ESS in the way the proportional seats are handed out, since under MMM, both constituency and proportional seats are considered completely separately: A party may win every single constituency seat and still receive its share of the proportional seats. ESS on the other hand considers the whole seat total to be shared proportionally; accordingly, the seats a party has won on the constituency level do play a role in the allocation of compensatory seats.
{{wpl|Mixed-member majoritarian representation|Mixed-Member Majoritarian}} systems differ from ESS in the way the proportional seats are handed out, since under MMM, both constituency and proportional seats are awarded completely separately: A party may win every single constituency seat and still receive its share of the proportional seats. ESS on the other hand considers the totality of the seats to be elected for its proportional component; accordingly, the seats a party has won on the constituency level do play a role in the allocation of compensatory ("top-up") seats.

Latest revision as of 17:27, 3 November 2023

The Evaluative Satisfaction System (ESS) is a mixed electoral system under which representatives in a multi-member body are elected on two tiers via a single round of evaluative voting. Representatives are first chosen in constituencies as the lower tier by using a majority approval vote; the overall composition of the body is then made to approach proportionality on the upper tier using a best-loser algorithm.

ESS is a semi-proportional electoral system, since parties might win more constituency seats in the lower tier than they would be proportionally entitled to in total, and the system does not compensate this by awarding other parties leveling seats to make a purely proportional result on the upper tier possible again. This issue typically affects elections where there are too few upper-tier seats in comparison to constituency seats.

The system was first developed for and used in the 2006 Council of the Union election with the intention to reduce incentives for strategic voting. It has drawn both praise and criticism: Supporters laud that its straightforward ballot layout makes casting one's vote accessible and ballots hard to spoil unintentionally, as well as that the multiple different tallies from each ballot make the election relatively resistent to strategic voting; critics however complain that this very fact also renders elections intransparent by making it hard for voters to precisely see how their vote will influence ‒ and, even after polls close, how it actually did affect ‒ the results.

Procedure

An ESS Ballot for the 2022 Council of the Union election

Under ESS, each voter casts a single evaluative voting ballot: Any number of candidates they approve or disapprove of may be marked, with the option to avoid marking a candidate altogether to express indifference. Candidates may be linked to a party list or stand as independents.

Lower tier

In the first step of the election procedure, representatives are determined on the constituency level as the lower-tier seats. Each constituency elects at least one representative, but there is no theoretical limit on the number of representatives a constituency could elect. There isn't a strict need to have multiple constituencies, either ‒ for small-scale elections, having just a single multi-seat constituency is equally viable, but the number of candidates standing can grow quite quickly with an increasing amount of constituency seats, thus limiting the practicability of single-constituency elections.

The exact method used to elect representatives is evaluative voting: Voters mark both all candidates they approve of and all they disapprove of, with the option to abstan from evaluating a candidate altogether. Approvals and disapprovals are tallied up for each candidate, and the candidate(s) with the highest net approval ‒ calculated by subtracting the number of disapprovals they received from the number of approvals received ‒ win(s) the constituency's seat(s).

Upper tier

The second step, electing the upper-tier compensatory seats, works in a slightly more complicated way. First, the parties eligible for receiving compensatory seats need to be determined ‒ the Tepertopian implementation requires that a party's candidates cross a certain approval threshold, for which the lower-tier approvals are considered. If parliamentary fragmentation isn't too large a concern, an implementation could also just consider all parties eligible.

With the eligible parties determined, ballots are re-counted to determine the electorate's so-called satisfaction with the candidates of the eligible parties. Each voter's satisfaction is divided equally between all candidates they approved and who stand for eligible parties ‒ approvals towards independent candidates or candidates standing for ineligible parties are ignored. The satisfaction received by each candidates is then pooled for the associated parties to determine the overall satisfaction shares of the parties. Those relative shares then constitute the share of seats the party is ideally entitled to at-large.

Once the shares stand, the compensatory upper-tier seats are handed out to the parties iteratively: Until all seats are filled, the most-underrepresented party (determined by the difference between its satisfaction share and current total seat share ‒ including those won on the lower tier) sees its least-disapproved candidate elected. Since upper-tier seats rely on unelected lower-tier candidates, parties have an incentive to stand candidates in as many constituencies as possible.

Example

The constituency of Examplington encompasses the entire eponymous city, for which the three-seat municipal council is to be elected using ESS. Two parties (green and yellow) and one independent vie for the votes of the ten voters. Two of the three seats are to be elected on the lower, the remaining one on the upper tier.

The ballots come in as follows:

Ballots
Candidate
. A
. B
. C
. D
. E
Approval = | Disapproval =

Lower tier

According to the results above, the candidate's net approval scores are as follows:

Candidate Approvals Disapprovals Net Approval
. A 4 0 +4
. B 4 3 + 2 -1
. C 3 4 + 1 -2
. D 3 + 1 2 +2
. E 2 + 1 0 +3

As candidates A and E have the highest net approval, they are elected as representatives on the lower tier.

Upper tier

For the purposes of demonstration, Examplington qualifies all parties for compensatory seats without any restrictions. The independent E however does not play any role for upper-tier allocation, since only party-affiliated candidates are considered ‒ the two voters whose only positive approval went towards E are consequently completely removed from upper-tier calculations. As such, the satisfaction shares divide as such:

Ballots
Candidate
Candidate Satisfaction Party Satisfaction Party Share
. A 0.5 2 4 50%
. B 0.5 2
. C 0.5 1.5 4 50%
. D 0.5 1 2.5
Total: 8 100%

In terms of party satisfaction, the parties are split evenly ‒ which makes sense, considering that there were four ballots from voters only supporting the green party, three only supporting the yellow party, and one that supported a yellow party candidate (and the ‒ irrelevant ‒ independent). These vote shares determine the further procedure of the compensation algorithm, which runs the following steps once per seat to fill ‒ in this case, only a single time, since only one seat remains to be filled on the council: First, the current share of seats each party has is determined, and then, the party with the greater difference between entitled and current seat share is awarded the seat.

Party Current Seats Current Share Entitled Share Difference
Green 1 1/3 = 33% 50% 12%
Yellow 0 0/3 = 0% 50% 50%

As the yellow party is more under-represented than the green party, it is awarded the seat. Within the party, the seat goes to the least-disapproved candidate from among the constituency candidates ‒ in this case, candidate C from the yellow party received 5 disapprovals for a total disapproval rate of 50%, and candidate D received 2 for a rate of 20%. As such, the final seat is filled by candidate D.

This means that the municipal council of Examplington will have A from the green and D from the yellow party, as well as the independent E.

Differences to Other Voting Systems

MMP

Unlike the Mixed-Member Proportional system, ESS does not natively accomodate for overhang seats ‒ since the system works on an iterative, relative share basis with a fixed number of seats, other parties are actively harmed by a party winning more seats on the lower tier than it would be entitled to on the upper: If a party would be entitled to 50% of the seats, but its competitor already won a total of 60% in constituencies, a 100-seat parliament would be split 60-40 in seats under the ESS, while MMP would still award the party its absolute 50 seats for a final 60-50 seat split. Some versions of MMP would furthermore fully compensate overhang seats with leveling seats for the other parties, which would result in a fully proportional 60-60 seat split in the former example. Effectively, the ESS sacrifices this full proportionality in order to avoid ever-growing seat numbers stemming from overhang and leveling seats.

Furthermore, most MMP implementations separate the candidate and the party vote, allowing voters to support local candidates without giving votes to the associated party (split-ticket voting), whereas ESS only exposes the candidates to voter approval and automatically converts their performance to party support to avoid decoy lists. However, ESS gives voters more options for influencing the order in which compensatory seats are awarded to candidates by using their disapproval rate, whereas MMP often features a closed list, with the political parties fixing the order in which they want to have candidates elected in advance.

AMS

ESS is very similar to the Additional-Member System, which works the exact same on the overhang seat issue. Strictly speaking, ESS could be considered a variant of the AMS adapted to the use of Evaluative Voting. However, AMS too often features split-ticket voting and closed party lists.

MMM

Mixed-Member Majoritarian systems differ from ESS in the way the proportional seats are handed out, since under MMM, both constituency and proportional seats are awarded completely separately: A party may win every single constituency seat and still receive its share of the proportional seats. ESS on the other hand considers the totality of the seats to be elected for its proportional component; accordingly, the seats a party has won on the constituency level do play a role in the allocation of compensatory ("top-up") seats.